“Globalization” is a popular term for what is happening in the contemporary political economy, and is often treated as if it were something utterly new. Only when considering trends over the past century can we describe globalization as even relatively new, deepening in its importance since 1945.
But this, of course, does not represent the first wave of globalization. The period from World War I through the Great Depression and World War II can be considered a hiatus between the great century of globalization 1815-1914 and the period after 1945. Many economists and liberal international political economists label this earlier period as the ‘first globalization.’
I prefer to refer to the period of European expansion during the three centuries prior to that, often called the Age of Exploration, as the first globalization. The reason liberals do not consider this wave of globalization on par with the other two is because it is a period dominated not by liberal free trade, but by massive corporate monopolies, like the British and Dutch East India Companies, and extensive government regulation of trade through tariffs, prohibitions, and restrictive laws like the Navigation Acts.
My renumbering results in the great mercantile era of the 16th through the 18th centuries being the first globalization. I detail its characteristics in Chapter 7 of my book, International Political Economy: The Business of War and Peace. The first great liberal globalization I designate as the ‘second globalization,’ which I examine in chapters 8 and 9 (including its shift into imperialism). Part IV, the last 5 chapters of my book, describe the foundations of the modern world order, or the ‘third globalization,’ or what also call the age of business internationalism.
It is useful to distinguish these three in order to consider similarities and differences. There are many to consider, but for now I will focus only on the roots of deflationary pressures during our current phase of contemporary globalization.
The first globalization led to a ballooning of debt as the various powers borrowed more and more to fight for shares of world commerce. The original front-runners, Spain and Portugal, were soon eclipsed by the Netherlands, a spectacular financial innovator. The Netherlands is the first place in the world to raise enormous joint-stock companies, develop deep financial markets, deploy massive privately-owned global fleets, and where financial capital became so abundant that commercial interest rates fell below 2 percent, far below any previous level in world history.
However, cheap credit was used by states to raise increasingly larger armies and navies, and little Netherlands fell behind France and Britain in this race. Britain won out by 1815 largely because its much superior financial system enabled it to borrow at 3 percent while the French borrowed at 5 or 6 percent. The enormous burden of French debt would, in turn, lead directly to the French Revolution.
Whereas the first globalization was characterized by a huge accumulation of debt and eventually inflation, the second globalization was the opposite. During the 19th century, cost of trade fell precipitously both because of technological development, such as the railroad and the steamship, but also because of the near elimination of piracy, a stable international monetary system, and trade freer of government and private monopoly restrictions. The century after 1815 included few major wars, so government debt levels fell, especially in Britain and in the U.S., before its Civil War.
Whereas the first globalization included a debt bubble and consequent price inflation, during the second globalization, debt expanded less and prices fell, especially after Civil War. By 1900, most prices were below and some much below 1800. The longest deflation in world history would follow from the 1860s through the 1890s.
Deflation is a serious problem for debtors, as I have said before in this column. It means debts, mostly fixed in money terms, do not go down, but the prices of most other things do. Therefore the incomes of debtors fall but their debt does not, a recipe for bankruptcy and default. In fact, there were thousands of bankruptcies worldwide, especially during the last third of the 19th century, including nearly all the American railroad companies. Creditors (i.e. the big banks) then took over the bankrupt companies and typically reorganized them into massive corporations and conglomerates, many of which survive today.
Thus during the 19th century government debt levels were not particularly high, but many of the largest new private corporations, like railroad, steel, shipping, and canal companies, did go bankrupt as prices fell and debts did not. (By the way, the “solution” for steel and allied industries was a massive worldwide naval arms race that started during the 1890s.)
Today, we are in the midst of the third globalization, which shares characteristics of the other two. Like the first globalization, this one includes a massive debt bubble, both public and private. This debt bubble has fueled high demand and high growth, leading to the unprecedented worldwide prosperity of the postwar era. This debt expansion alone tends to be inflationary. Indeed, inflation seemed the paramount economic challenge into the 1980s. Many politicians and some central bankers still obsess about it. Old habits die hard.
The reason inflation is now under control is not because of brilliant economic management under the guidance of the superior minds of economists. Far from it. It is because this era also shares characteristics with the second globalization, including massive deflationary pressures, that tend to counteract the inflationary pressures of the accelerating debt bubble.
Ben Bernanke, former Fed chair, often spoke of this era as the “Great Moderation,” since inflation seemed under control even while growth continued to boom. It seemed economic science was really working very well. Then 2008 surprised most economists who pay little attention to issues of debt, especially private debt. Thus the current era is not necessarily one of moderation, but rather a delicate balance between two extremes. The massive surge in debt has created inflationary pressures, but sometimes these manifest more in asset markets, like stocks or real estate, rather than in the prices of ordinary goods.
The reason goods prices do not tend to inflate is that strong deflationary pressures tend to push prices down. These deflationary pressures have similar roots to those of the 19th century. On the one hand, they are technological. Computer memory, in accord with Moore’s Law, has become vastly cheaper in recent decades, leading to an explosive growth in nearly free worldwide communication and facilitating information processing and remote management. Transportation costs have similarly fallen significantly.
Freeing the global of trade restrictions, including the demise of the Soviet Bloc and the opening of China to world trade, have greatly lowered the real cost of goods as more and more products are produced in the cheapest place possible and traded around the globe. Free trade itself tends to cause deflation. Interestingly, today in the U.S., the foremost sources of inflation are in medical care, education and real estate, none of which are much affected by the deflationary trade pressures since these things are not tradable.
The future of the world economy depends on which tendency predominates: credit-fueled inflation or technology- and trade-induced deflation. During the 1930s, countries closed themselves more and more to trade in order to reverse the deflation brought on by the Great Depression. On the other hand, if trade stays free and the debt bubble collapses, deflationary pressures will push the world into a debt-deflationary depression. For these reasons, we live in an age, not of Great Moderation, but of countervailing extremes.